Untitled Diff

Created Diff never expires


Gender Differences in Recognition for Group Work
Gender Differences in Recognition for Group Work
Heather Sarsons
Heather Sarsons, Klarita Gërxhani, Ernesto Reuben, and Arthur Schram
February 4, 2019
September 15, 2019
Abstract
Abstract
Does gender influence how credit for group work is allocated? Using data from
Does gender influence how credit for group work is allocated? Using data from
academic economists’ CVs, I test whether coauthored and solo-authored publications
academic economists’ CVs, we test whether coauthored and solo-authored publica-
matter differently for tenure for men and women. Because coauthors are listed alpha-
tions matter differently for tenure for men and women. Because coauthors are listed
betically in economics, coauthored papers do not provide specific information about
alphabetically in economics, coauthored papers do not provide specific information
each contributor’s skills or ability. Solo-authored papers, on the other hand, provide
about each contributor’s skills or ability. Solo-authored papers, on the other hand,
a relatively clear signal of ability. I find that conditional on publication quality and
provide a relatively clear signal of ability. We find that conditional on publication
other observables, men are tenured at roughly the same rate regardless of whether
quality and other observables, men are tenured at roughly the same rate regardless of
they coauthor or solo-author. Women, however, become less likely to receive tenure
whether they coauthor or solo-author. Women, however, become less likely to receive
the more they coauthor. The result is most pronounced for women coauthoring with
tenure the more they coauthor. The result is most pronounced for women coauthoring
men and less pronounced among women who coauthor with other women. An on-
with men and less pronounced among women who coauthor with other women. Two
line experiment finds similar patterns when women perform male-stereotyped tasks.
experiments suggest that both stereotypes surrounding a task as well as the evalua-
However, women receive equal credit for joint work with men when the task is per-
tors’ gender affect who receives credit. Taken together, our results are best explained
ceived to be gender-neutral. Taken together, the results suggest that gender and stereo-
by gender and stereotypes having a noticeable influence on the allocation of credit for
types influence the allocation of credit for group work.
group work.
I especially thank Roland Fryer, Claudia Goldin, Larry Katz, David Laibson, and Amanda Pallais for
Sarsons, University of Chicago Booth (heather.sarsons@chicagobooth.edu); Gërxhani, European Uni-
their guidance and encouragement. I also thank Mitra Akhtari, Amitabh Chandra, John Coglianese, Oren
versity Institute; Reuben, New York University Abu Dhabi and LISER; Schram, Amsterdam School of Eco-
Danieli, Ellora Derenoncourt, Florian Ederer, Ben Enke, Raissa Fabregas, Nicole Fortin, Peter Ganong, Ed-
nomics and European University Institute. Sarsons especially thanks Roland Fryer, Claudia Goldin, Larry
ward Glaeser, Siri Isaksson, Sara Lowes, Rob McMillan, Eduardo Montero, Gautam Rao, Alex Segura, Nihar
Katz, David Laibson, and Amanda Pallais for their guidance and encouragement. We also thank Mitra
Shah, Peter Tu, Justin Wolfers, and participants at SOLE 2016, the Early Behavioural Economics Conference,
Akhtari, Amitabh Chandra, John Coglianese, Oren Danieli, Ellora Derenoncourt, Florian Ederer, Ben Enke,
the Harvard Business School Gender Initiative, and the Harvard Inequality Seminar for helpful comments
Raissa Fabregas, Nicole Fortin, Nickolas Gagnon, Peter Ganong, Edward Glaeser, Siri Isaksson, Emir Ka-
and suggestions. This paper is intentionally solo-authored.
menica, Sara Lowes, Rob McMillan, Eduardo Montero, Gautam Rao, Alex Segura, Nihar Shah, Peter Tu,
Jeroen van de Ven, Justin Wolfers, and various conference and seminar participants for their helpful com-
ments and suggestions.
1
1


1 Introduction
1 Introduction
Do employers use gender when allocating credit for group work, particularly when in-
Do employers use gender when allocating credit for group work, particularly when in-
dividual contributions are unobserved? Organizations increasingly rely on group work
dividual contributions are unobserved? Organizations increasingly rely on group work
for production (Lazear and Shaw, 2007), yet there is little empirical evidence document-
for production (Lazear and Shaw, 2007), yet there is little empirical evidence document-
ing how credit for group work is allocated. Unless employers can perfectly observe each
ing how credit for group work is allocated. Unless employers can perfectly observe each
worker’s contribution to the team’s output, they must decide how to allocate credit with-
worker’s contribution to the team’s output, they must decide how to allocate credit with-
out having full information as to what each worker did. This could leave room for demo-
out having full information as to what each worker did. This could leave room for demo-
graphic characteristics, such as gender, to influence the allocation of credit.
graphic characteristics, such as gender, to influence the allocation of credit.
In this paper, I test whether uncertainty over an individual’s contribution to a project
In this paper, we test whether uncertainty over an individual’s contribution to a project
leads to differential attribution of credit that contributes to the gender promotion gap. In
leads to differential attribution of credit that contributes to the gender promotion gap. In
many industries, women are not only hired at lower rates than men are, they are also
many industries, women are not only hired at lower rates than men are, they are also
promoted at lower rates.
promoted at lower rates.
1
1
This paper explores whether gender differences in credit for
This paper explores whether gender differences in credit for
group work exist and whether they explain part of the promotion gap.
group work exist and whether they explain part of the promotion gap.
I primarily look at the tenure decisions of academic economists to test whether gender
We primarily look at the tenure decisions of academic economists to test whether gen-
influences the allocation of credit for coauthored papers. Economics is a relevant setting
der influences the allocation of credit for coauthored papers. Economics is a relevant
as there is a large tenure gap between men and women, and because the amount of coau-
setting as there is a large tenure gap between men and women, and because the amount
thoring has risen dramatically in recent years (Ginther and Kahn, 2004; Hammermesh,
of coauthoring has risen dramatically in recent years (Ginther and Kahn, 2004; Hammer-
2013). Using data from economists’ CVs, I track individuals’ career trajectories and com-
mesh, 2013). Using data from economists’ CVs, we track individuals’ career trajectories
pare whether the trajectory is different for individuals who coauthor versus solo-author,
and compare whether the trajectory is different for individuals who coauthor versus solo-
and whether there is a difference by gender.
author, and whether there is a difference by gender.
Within economics, I find that men and women who solo-author most of their work
Within economics, we find that men and women who solo-author most of their work
have similar tenure rates conditional on a proxy for the quality of papers. However, an
have similar tenure rates conditional on a proxy for the quality of papers. However, an
additional coauthored paper is correlated with an 8.2% increase in tenure probability for
additional coauthored paper is correlated with an 8.2% increase in tenure probability for
men but only a 5.6% increase for women. This gap is significantly less pronounced for
men but only a 5.6% increase for women. This gap is significantly less pronounced for
women who coauthor with women, suggesting that the attribution of credit is related
women who coauthor with women, suggesting that the attribution of credit is related
to the gender mix of coauthors. Furthermore, a man who coauthors is no less likely to
to the gender mix of coauthors. Furthermore, a man who coauthors is no less likely to
receive tenure than a comparable man who solo-authors even though there is presumably
receive tenure than a comparable man who solo-authors even though there is presumably
more uncertainty as to how much work he did. A counterfactual exercise suggests that
more uncertainty as to how much work he did. A counterfactual exercise suggests that
this difference in credit allocation explains 60% of the unconditional gender gap in tenure
this difference in credit allocation explains 60% of the unconditional gender gap in tenure
rates and 84% of the gap that remains after controlling for average paper quality, citations,
rates and 84% of the gap that remains after controlling for average paper quality, citations,
tenure and PhD institution ranks, and field.
tenure and PhD institution ranks, and field.
To ensure that I am not picking up on ability differences between men and women, I
To ensure that we are not picking up on ability differences between men and women,
control for the quality of papers using both journal rankings and citations, allowing for
we control for the quality of papers using both journal rankings and citations, allowing
1
1
Blau and DeVaro (2007), for example, find that across jobs, women are less likely to be promoted than
Blau and DeVaro (2007), for example, find that across jobs, women are less likely to be promoted than
men conditional on worker’s performance and ability ratings. In the UK, female managers are nearly 40%
men conditional on worker’s performance and ability ratings. In the UK, female managers are nearly 40%
less likely to be promoted than male managers (Elmins et al. 2016).
less likely to be promoted than male managers (Elmins et al., 2016).
2
2


a comparison of men and women with similar research portfolios. The results are also
for a comparison of men and women with similar research portfolios. The results are also
robust to including other individual-level controls such as length of time to tenure and
robust to including other individual-level controls such as length of time to tenure and the
the seniority of one’s coauthors, as well as tenure year, tenure institution, and primary
seniority of one’s coauthors, as well as tenure year, tenure institution, and primary field
field fixed effects.
fixed effects.
I argue that these results are most consistent with a story of women receiving less credit
We argue that these results are most consistent with a story of women receiving less
for their joint work with men because of bias. To show this, I first use current CV and
credit for their joint work with men because of bias. To show this, we first use current
citation data to compare the productivity of men and women who did and did not receive
CV and citation data to compare the productivity of men and women who did and did
tenure at the institution where they initially went up for tenure. While the estimates are
not receive tenure at the institution where they initially went up for tenure. While the
imprecise, I find suggestive evidence that women who coauthor and are denied tenure
estimates are imprecise, we find suggestive evidence that women who coauthor and are
produce more solo-authored papers that publish in high-ranking journals than men who
denied tenure produce more solo-authored papers that publish in high-ranking journals
are denied tenure. Data on citations show a similar result.
than men who are denied tenure. Data on citations show a similar result.
I then rule out several alternative explanations for the empirical patterns. For example,
We then rule out several alternative explanations for the empirical patterns. For ex-
several papers have demonstrated that selection into coauthorship in economics is not
ample, several papers have demonstrated that selection into coauthorship in economics
random.
is not random.
2
2
I test for selection into coauthorship and do not find any evidence that women
We test for selection into coauthorship and do not find any evidence that
coauthor with high ability or more senior men. I also look at the timing of coauthorship
women coauthor with high ability or more senior men. We also look at the timing of coau-
and find no evidence that women begin coauthoring if they have a slower start to their
thorship and find no evidence that women begin coauthoring if they have a slower start
careers. The empirical patterns are also inconsistent with taste-basted discrimination.
to their careers. The empirical patterns are also inconsistent with taste-basted discrimina-
Because the CV data does not allow me to rule out the possibility that women actually
tion.
contribute less to papers that are coauthored with men, I conduct an online experiment
Because the CV data do not allow us to rule out the possibility that women actually
designed to test whether this drives credit allocation. In the experiment, I first hire indi-
contribute less to papers that are coauthored with men, we conduct two experiments de-
viduals to complete quizzes on topics that are either male or female-stereotyped. I then
signed to test whether real or perceived differences in contributions drive credit allocation.
hire participants who act as “predictors” and are randomized into a solo treatment or a
In the first experiment, we first hire individuals to complete quizzes on topics that are ei-
group treatment. Predictors in the solo treatment are shown two individual’s separate
ther male or female-stereotyped. We then hire participants who act as “predictors” and
quiz scores while predictors in the group treatment are shown the combined score of two
are randomized into an individual treatment or a joint treatment. Predictors in the indi-
individuals. They are then asked to predict the performance of each participant on future
vidual treatment are shown two individual’s separate quiz scores while predictors in the
quizzes.
joint treatment are shown the combined score of two individuals. They are then asked to
I find that in the group treatment, women are predicted to perform worse than their
predict the performance of each participant on future quizzes.
male counterparts for male-stereotyped quizzes, suggesting that participants making the
In the joint treatment, women are predicted to perform worse than their male counter-
predictions believe that women contributed less to the combined score (that is, they per-
parts for male-stereotyped quizzes, suggesting that predictors believe that women con-
formed worse). However, if pairs performed a female-stereotyped quiz, women and men
tributed less to the combined score (that is, they performed worse). However, if pairs
are given equal credit. To understand whether these results are driven by participants’
performed a female-stereotyped quiz, women and men are given equal credit. To under-
beliefs about the ability distributions of men and women, I randomly provide some par-
stand whether these results are driven by participants’ beliefs about the ability distribu-
tions of men and women, we randomly provide some participants with the distribution of
scores on the initial quiz by gender. Women appear to be given equal credit in the female-
stereotyped quiz because participants view it as being gender-neutral. That is, they do not
2
2
Boschini and Sjögren (2007) test whether coauthorship patterns in economics are gender neutral. They
See, for example, Boschini and Sjögren (2007), Garcia and Sherman (2015), and Bikard et al (2015).
find that women are more likely to solo-author than men and that gender homophily in coauthoring in-
creases with women’s representation in a field. Garcia and Sherman (2015) argue that the alphabetical pub-
lishing norms in economics influence both the types of people authors work with and the types of projects
they will work on.
3
3


ticipants with the distribution of scores on the initial quiz by gender. Women appear to
realize that women tend to outperform men. Showing participants the gender distribution
be given equal credit in the female-stereotyped quiz because participants view it as being
of scores corrects this belief and women are then predicted to have a better performance
gender-neutral. That is, they do not realize that women tend to outperform men. Show-
in future female-stereotyped quizzes but it does not affect the predicted performance gap
ing participants the gender distribution of scores corrects this belief and women are then
for women and men performing male-stereotyped tasks.
predicted to have a better performance in future female-stereotyped quizzes. Surpris-
The second experiment is conducted in a more natural setting with human resources
ingly, this treatment does not affect the predicted performance gap for women and men
personnel. Following a similar design, we again test whether women are less likely than
performing male-stereotyped tasks.
men to receive credit for good group performance. We additionally elicit the HR person-
nels’ beliefs about male and female performance and find that differences in the allocation
of credit are largely driven by differences in beliefs. We also find that male HR personnel
are more likely to hire in favor of men, and women in favor of women.
This paper replicates and builds off of the results in Sarsons (2017), which shows the
This paper replicates and builds off of the results in Sarsons (2017), which shows the
basic correlational patterns between paper composition and tenure. In this paper, I repli-
basic correlational patterns between paper composition and tenure. In this paper, we
cate the results using more data and then use the C.V. data and an experiment to establish a
replicate the results using more data and then use the C.V. data and two experiments to es-
channel through which gender influences the allocation of credit. The paper also relates to
tablish a channel through which gender influences the allocation of credit. The paper also
a large literature seeking to understand difference in labor market outcomes between men
relates to a large literature seeking to understand difference in labor market outcomes be-
and women. Factors such as productivity, personality and behavioural differences (such
tween men and women. Factors such as productivity, personality and behavioural differ-
as competition aversion), and fertility preferences have been shown to explain some differ-
ences (such as competition aversion), and fertility preferences have been shown to explain
ences in career choice and progression.
some differences in career choice and progression.
3
3
In academia in particular, studies have pointed
In academia in particular, studies have
to both supply-side factors, including differences in subject matter interest (Dynan and
pointed to both supply-side factors, including differences in subject matter interest (Dy-
Rouse, 1997) and the availability of role models (Hale and Regev, 2014; Carrell, Page, and
nan and Rouse, 1997) and the availability of role models (Hale and Regev, 2014; Carrell et
West, 2010); demand-side factors, such as implicit bias (Milkman, Akinola, and Chugh,
al., 2010); demand-side factors, such as implicit bias (Milkman et al., 2015; Moss-Racusin et
2015; Moss-Racusin et al., 2012); and institutional factors (Antecol et al., 2018). This paper
al., 2012); and institutional factors (Antecol et al., 2018). This paper directly tests whether
directly tests whether the differential treatment of work output contributes to the gender
the differential treatment of work output contributes to the gender gap.
gap.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and
shows that a tenure gap exists between male and female economists. In Section 3, I show
shows that a tenure gap exists between male and female economists. In Section 3, we
that the tenure gap closes as women produce more solo-authored papers but does not
show that the tenure gap closes as women produce more solo-authored papers but does
close as they produce more coauthored papers. Women have a consistently lower proba-
not close as they produce more coauthored papers. Women have a consistently lower
bility of tenure for each additional coauthored paper than men. I show that the results are
probability of tenure for each additional coauthored paper than men. We show that the
robust to accounting for attrition, and to using different journal rankings and definitions
results are robust to accounting for attrition, and to using different journal rankings and
of tenure. In Section 4, I argue that the results are in line with a story in which women
definitions of tenure. In Section 4, we argue that the results are in line with a story in which
receive less credit for joint work with men. I test alternative explanations of the relation-
women receive less credit for joint work with men. We test alternative explanations of the
ship between coauthorship and tenure and argue that none can fully explain the observed
relationship between coauthorship and tenure and argue that none can fully explain the
empirical patterns. Section 5 discusses the structure and results of the experiment. Section
observed empirical patterns. Section 5 discusses the design and results of the experiments.
6 concludes.
Section 6 concludes.
3
3
There is a large literature documenting gender differences in productivity, attitudes toward different
There is a large literature documenting gender differences in productivity, attitudes toward different
types of work, and family choices. See, for example, Niederle and Vesterlund (2007), Antecol et al. (2016),
types of work, and family choices. See, for example, Niederle and Vesterlund (2007), Buser et al. (2014),
Ceci et al. (2014), and Ginther and Kahn (2004).
Antecol et al. (2018), Ceci et al. (2014), Reuben et al. (2017), and Ginther and Kahn (2004).
4
4


2 Data
2 Data
To examine the relationship between paper composition and tenure, I construct a dataset
To examine the relationship between paper composition and tenure, we construct a dataset
using the CVs of economists who came up for tenure between 1985 and 2014 at one of the
using the CVs of economists who came up for tenure between 1985 and 2014 at one of the
top 35 U.S. PhD-granting universities
top 35 U.S. PhD-granting universities
4
4
. The academic progression documented in the CVs
. The academic progression documented in the CVs
makes it possible to evaluate the relationship between an individual’s research output and
makes it possible to evaluate the relationship between an individual’s research output and
career progression. I can then compare the degree of collaborative work and reward for
career progression. We can then compare the degree of collaborative work and reward for
that work, and compare these results for men versus women.
that work, and compare these results for men versus women.
2.1 Sample Selection and Data Overview
2.1 Sample Selection and Data Overview
I include only PhD-granting institutions in the sample as tenure evaluation at these schools
We include only PhD-granting institutions in the sample as tenure evaluation at these
is primarily based on research output, of which I have a clear measure. Other institutions
schools is primarily based on research output, of which we have a clear measure. Other
like liberal arts colleges place greater weight on teaching ability for tenure, something
institutions like liberal arts colleges place greater weight on teaching ability for tenure,
that I cannot measure. I exclude business and public policy schools for similar reasons.
something that we cannot measure. We exclude business and public policy schools for
similar reasons.
5
5
It is reasonable to assume that the top 35 economics departments in the U.S. emphasize
It is reasonable to assume that the top 35 economics departments in
research which is measured by the number and quality of papers one produces.
the U.S. emphasize research which is measured by the number and quality of papers one
produces.
One problem in collecting tenure information is that the CVs of individuals who went
One problem in collecting tenure information is that the CVs of individuals who went
up for tenure, were denied it, and left to industry or government are difficult to find, lead-
up for tenure, were denied it, and left to industry or government are difficult to find, lead-
ing to a sample selection problem. To deal with this issue, I collected historical faculty lists
ing to a sample selection problem. To deal with this issue, we collected historical faculty
from 23 of the 35 schools and locate over 90% of faculty who had ever gone up for tenure
lists from 23 of the 35 schools and locate over 90% of faculty who had ever gone up for
at these 23 institutions. For the remaining 12 schools that did not have historical faculty
tenure at these 23 institutions. For the remaining 12 schools that did not have historical
lists available, I looked at the top 75 U.S. institutions, the top 5 Canadian institutions, and
faculty lists available, we looked at the top 75 U.S. institutions, the top 5 Canadian institu-
the top 5 European institutions to locate anyone who went up for tenure at a top 35 U.S.
tions, and the top 5 European institutions to locate anyone who went up for tenure at a top
school and then moved to another institution. I also checked economists’ CVs at the ma-
35 U.S. school and then moved to another institution. We also checked economists’ CVs at
jor Federal Reserve Boards and other large research institutes, such as Mathematica, in the
the major Federal Reserve Boards and other large research institutes, such as Mathemat-
U.S. While there might still be a sample selection problem, I show in Section 3.2.1 that the
ica, in the U.S. While there might still be a sample selection problem, we show in Section
results are robust to using only the sample for which I have historical faculty lists.
3.2.1 that the results are robust to using only the sample for which we have historical
From individuals’ CVs, I code where and when they received their PhDs, their em-
faculty lists.
From individuals’ CVs, we code where and when they received their PhDs, their em-
ployment and publication history, and their primary and secondary fields. When looking
ployment and publication history, and their primary and secondary fields. When looking
at the relationship between publications and tenure in the main analysis, I only include
at the relationship between publications and tenure in the main analysis, we only include
papers that were published up to and including the year an individual goes up for tenure.
Book chapters are not included in the paper count. In a robustness check, I include papers
that were published one and two years after tenure.
4
4
The list of institutions are taken from the RePEc/IDEAS Economics Department rankings. The list of
The list of institutions are taken from the RePEc/IDEAS Economics Department rankings. The list of
schools included can be found in Appendix A
schools included can be found in Appendix C.
5
5
Business and policy schools might also value teaching differently and put weight on different types of
Business and policy schools might also value teaching differently and put weight on different types of
journals.
journals.
5
5


To control for the quality of a person’s publications, I primarily use the “AER equiv-
papers that were published up to and including the year an individual goes up for tenure.
Book chapters are not included in the paper count. In a robustness check, we include
papers that were published one and two years after tenure.
To control for the quality of a person’s publications, we primarily use the “AER equiv-
alent” ranking measure developed by Kalaitzidakis et al. (2003). This measure converts
alent” ranking measure developed by Kalaitzidakis et al. (2003). This measure converts
journal publications into their equivalent number of American Economic Review papers
journal publications into their equivalent number of American Economic Review papers.
6
6
.
Less than 10% of journal articles cannot be converted because the journal does not appear
Less than 10% of journal articles cannot be converted because the journal does not appear
in the ranking. In these cases I give the publication a ranking of zero.
in the ranking. In these cases we give the publication a ranking of zero.
7
7
Using the AER-equivalent measure instead of a list journal rank allows for different
Using the AER-equivalent measure instead of a list journal rank allows for different
distances between journal ranks and for multiple journals to hold the same rank. For
distances between journal ranks and for multiple journals to hold the same rank. For
example, the top field journals can all hold the same rank. Other journal rankings force
example, the top field journals can all hold the same rank. Other journal rankings force
a ranking among these even though the journals might count the same amount toward
a ranking among these even though the journals might count the same amount toward
tenure depending on one’s field. For robustness, I replace this paper quality measure
tenure depending on one’s field. For robustness, we replace this paper quality measure
with the RePEc/IDEAS ranking of economics journals in Section 3.2.2.
with the RePEc/IDEAS ranking of economics journals in Section 3.2.2.
Finally, I include citations, measured in 2015, of pre-tenure papers as a control variable.
Finally, we include citations, measured in 2015, of pre-tenure papers as a control vari-
These citations were scraped from Google Scholar.
able. These citations were scraped from Google Scholar.
I supplement this dataset with results from a survey designed to measure individuals’
We supplement this dataset with results from a survey designed to measure individu-
beliefs about the returns to various types of papers. The survey also contains information
als’ beliefs about the returns to various types of papers. The survey also contains informa-
on how frequently individuals present their papers. The exact questions and nature of the
tion on how frequently individuals present their papers. The exact questions and nature
survey are discussed in greater detail in Section 4.
of the survey are discussed in greater detail in Section 4.
2.2 Construction of Tenure
2.2 Construction of Tenure
To determine whether someone received tenure, I follow the guidelines on each school’s
To determine whether someone received tenure, we follow the guidelines on each school’s
website (as of 2015) as to when tenure decisions are made. The majority of schools require
website (as of 2015) as to when tenure decisions are made. The majority of schools require
faculty to apply for tenure 7 years after their initial appointment. I therefore consider
faculty to apply for tenure 7 years after their initial appointment. We therefore consider
years 6-8 to be the “tenure window” in which someone applies for tenure to account for
years 6-8 to be the “tenure window” in which someone applies for tenure to account for
people who go up for tenure early or late (because of a leave of absence, for example). I as-
people who go up for tenure early or late (because of a leave of absence, for example).
sume that an individual is denied tenure if s/he moves to a university ranked 5 positions
We assume that an individual is denied tenure if s/he moves to a university ranked 5
below the initial institution during the tenure window. Similarly, I assume that an indi-
positions below the initial institution during the tenure window. Similarly, we assume
vidual is denied tenure if he moves from academia to industry during the tenure window.
that an individual is denied tenure if s/he moves from academia to industry during the
Defining tenure in this way accounts for the fact that some people switch institutions 2-3
tenure window. Defining tenure in this way accounts for the fact that some people switch
years after their initial appointment, not because they were denied tenure but for personal
institutions 2-3 years after their initial appointment, not because they were denied tenure
preferences, and that some people might choose to move to a comparable school around
the time of tenure even though they were offered tenure at their original institution. For
6
6
The American Economic Review is regarded as one of the top journals in economics. Most journal
The American Economic Review is regarded as one of the top journals in economics. Most journal
publications are therefore converted to be some fraction of an AER paper.
publications are therefore converted to be some fraction of an AER paper.
7
7
If someone does not have any solo or coauthored papers, I set the relevant journal ranking to zero and
If someone does not have any solo or coauthored papers, we set the relevant journal ranking to zero and
include a dummy variable indicating that the individual has no solo (or coauthored) papers. This enables
include a dummy variable indicating that the individual has no solo (or coauthored) papers. This enables
me to keep using the full sample.
us to keep using the full sample.
6
6


example, someone who moves from MIT to Harvard after 7 years was presumably offered
but for personal preferences, and that some people might choose to move to a comparable
tenure at MIT but chose to move to Harvard for other reasons.
school around the time of tenure even though they were offered tenure at their original
institution. For example, someone who moves from MIT to Harvard after 7 years was
presumably offered tenure at MIT but chose to move to Harvard for other reasons.
As mentioned, a person who moves 5 or fewer years after his or her initial appointment
As mentioned, a person who moves 5 or fewer years after his or her initial appointment
is not assumed to have been denied tenure since s/he moved before the tenure window
is not assumed to have been denied tenure since s/he moved before the tenure window
starts. If someone moves before the tenure window, I use the second institution they were
starts. If someone moves before the tenure window, we use the second institution they
at to determine tenure. For example, if a person’s first job is at University A but s/he
were at to determine tenure. For example, if a person’s first job is at University A but s/he
moves to University B after three years, I use University B as the tenure institution but
moves to University B after three years, we use University B as the tenure institution but
do not start the tenure clock over. I do not restart the clock because the data shows that
do not start the tenure clock over. We do not restart the clock because the data shows that
in over 80% of cases, the individual still appears to go up for tenure within 8 years of his
in over 80% of cases, the individual still appears to go up for tenure within 8 years of his
or her appointment at the first institution. However, I do extend this tenure clock in a
or her appointment at the first institution. However, we do extend this tenure clock in a
robustness check.
robustness check.
Individuals who move from an academic institution into industry before the tenure
Individuals who move from an academic institution into industry before the tenure
window are excluded from the sample.
window are excluded from the sample.
2.3 Summary Statistics
2.3 Summary Statistics
Table 1 presents summary statistics of the data. Approximately 68% of the full sample
Table 1 presents summary statistics of the data. Approximately 68% of the full sample
received tenure, but this masks a stark difference between men and women. Only 52% of
received tenure, but this masks a stark difference between men and women. Only 52% of
women received tenure while 73% of men did.
women received tenure while 73% of men did.
Total Papers,Solo-authored, andCoauthoredare the number of papers in each group that
Total Papers,Solo-authored, andCoauthoredare the number of papers in each group that
an individual had published by the time of tenure. These publication counts do not in-
an individual had published by the time of tenure. These publication counts do not in-
clude books or book chapters. Papers published in non-economics journals (such as a
clude books or book chapters. Papers published in non-economics journals (such as a
political science journal) are included but receive a ranking of 0 (the lowest ranking). The
political science journal) are included but receive a ranking of 0 (the lowest ranking). The
results are robust to excluding publications in non-economics journals.
results are robust to excluding publications in non-economics journals.
There is no statistically significant difference in the number of papers that men and
There is no statistically significant difference in the number of papers that men and
women produce. Panel B looks at differences in the quality of papers. Men are no more
women produce. Panel B looks at differences in the quality of papers. Men are no more
likely to publish their papers in "Top 5" journals (American Economic Review, Economet-
likely to publish their papers in “Top 5” journals (American Economic Review, Economet-
rica, Journal of Political Economy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, and The Review of
rica, Journal of Political Economy, Quarterly Journal of Economics, and The Review of
Economic Studies) than women. The only statistically significant productivity difference
Economic Studies) than women. The only statistically significant productivity difference
is that men tend to publish their coauthored papers in slightly higher-ranking journals.
is that men tend to publish their coauthored papers in slightly higher-ranking journals.
Specifically, men’s coauthored papers have an average ranking of 0.34 AER-equivalents
Specifically, men’s coauthored papers have an average ranking of 0.34 AER-equivalents
while women’s coauthored papers have an average ranking of 0.30 AER-equivalents. I
while women’s coauthored papers have an average ranking of 0.30 AER-equivalents. We
therefore control for the quality of papers, measured using the AER-equivalent ranking as
therefore control for the quality of papers, measured using the AER-equivalent ranking as
well as average citations, throughout the analysis.
well as average citations, throughout the analysis.
Panel C displays differences in coauthoring patterns between men and women.Num-
ber Unique CAsis the number of unique coauthors an individual has had by tenure. Men
7
7


Panel C displays differences in coauthoring patterns between men and women.Num-
ber Unique CAsis the number of unique coauthors an individual has had by tenure. Men
and women have roughly the same number of coauthors but there are some differences in
and women have roughly the same number of coauthors but there are some differences in
the types of people men and women coauthor with. For example, women are less likely to
the types of people men and women coauthor with. For example, women are less likely to
coauthor with senior faculty and more likely to coauthor with other assistant professors.
coauthor with senior faculty and more likely to coauthor with other assistant professors.
This could in part be driven by the fact that they are also more likely to coauthor with
This could in part be driven by the fact that they are also more likely to coauthor with
other women, many of whom are also junior professors.
other women, many of whom are also junior professors.
For illustrative purposes, I plot the number of women and men who have various
For illustrative purposes, we plot the number of women and men who have various
combinations of solo and coauthored papers in Figure 1, as well as the average proba-
combinations of solo and coauthored papers in Figure 1, as well as the average probability
bility of receiving tenure for each paper combination in Figure 2. Most men and women
of receiving tenure for each paper combination in Figure 2. Most men and women have
have a similar combination of solo and coauthored papers. Figure 2 illustrates that in-
a similar combination of solo and coauthored papers. Figure 2 illustrates that individu-
dividuals with a large number of either solo or coauthored papers are likely to receive
als with a large number of either solo or coauthored papers are likely to receive tenure.
tenure. However, Panel A suggests that women with a higher fraction of their papers that
However, Panel A suggests that women with a higher fraction of their papers that are
are solo-authored have a better chance of receiving tenure than women with a mix of solo
solo-authored have a better chance of receiving tenure than women with a mix of solo
and coauthored papers. I examine this claim formally in the next section.
and coauthored papers. We examine this claim formally in the next section.
3 Empirical Strategy and Results
3 Empirical Strategy and Results
3.1 Main Results
3.1 Main Results
I show three main results. I first establish that a significant tenure gap exists between
We show three main results. We first establish that a significant tenure gap exists between
men and women. I then show that the gap becomes more pronounced the more women
men and women. We then show that the gap becomes more pronounced the more women
coauthor, and that women who solo-author all of their papers have comparable tenure
coauthor, and that women who solo-author all of their papers have comparable tenure
rates to men. Finally, I show that the gender of a woman’s coauthor matters. Women who
rates to men. Finally, we show that the gender of a woman’s coauthor matters. Women
coauthor with other women do not suffer a coauthor penalty.
who coauthor with other women do not suffer a coauthor penalty.
3.1.1 The Tenure Gap
3.1.1 The Tenure Gap
Figure 3 plots the coefficient
Figure 3 plots the coefficient
ˆ
ˆ
β
β
1
1
from estimating
from estimating
T
T
if st
if st
1
1
TotPapers
TotPapers
i
i
2
2
TotPapers
TotPapers
2
2
i
Z
Z
i
i
f
f
s
s
t
t
+
+
if st
if st
(1)
(1)
separately for men and women using OLS. The dependent variable,T
separately for men and women using OLS. The dependent variable,T
if st
if st
, is an indicator
, is an indicator
that individualiin fieldfat schoolsreceives tenure in yeart.TotPapers
that individualiin fieldfat schoolsreceives tenure in yeart.TotPapers
i
i
is the number of
is the number of
papers (both coauthored and solo-authored) individualihas at the time he or she went up
papers (both coauthored and solo-authored) individualihas at the time he or she went up
for tenure. A quadratic in the number of papers is included to capture non-linearities in
for tenure. A quadratic in the number of papers is included to capture non-linearities in
how publications matter for tenure. The vector of individual-level controls,Z
how publications matter for tenure. The vector of individual-level controls,Z
i
i
, includes
, includes
average journal rank (measured as average AER-equivalents), the log of total citations,
the number of years it tookito go up for tenure, and the average number of coauthors
8
8


oni’s papers. Tenure institution (θ
average journal rank (measured as average AER-equivalents), the log of total citations,
the number of years it tookito go up for tenure, and the total number of coauthors oni’s
papers. Tenure institution (θ
s
s
), tenure year (θ
), tenure year (θ
t
t
), and field fixed effects (θ
), and field fixed effects (θ
f
f
) are also
) are also included
included as tenure standards likely vary over time and by field and department.
as tenure standards likely vary over time and by field and department.
The figure shows that a significant tenure gap exists between men and women even
The figure shows that a significant tenure gap exists between men and women even
after controlling for productivity, primary field, tenure institution, and tenure year. While
after controlling for productivity, primary field, tenure institution, and tenure year. While
an additional paper is correlated with a 13-16 percentage point increase in tenure proba-
an additional paper is correlated with a 13-16 percentage point increase in tenure proba-
bility for men and women, women are consistently 10-13 percentage points less likely to
bility for men and women, women are consistently 10-13 percentage points less likely to
receive tenure than men conditional on having written the same number and quality of
receive tenure than men conditional on having written the same number and quality of
papers. The lower intercept for women could stem from tenure committees starting with a
papers. The lower intercept for women could stem from tenure committees starting with a
lower prior about women’s ability. However, if all papers were clear signals of ability and
lower prior about women’s ability. However, if all papers were clear signals of ability and
tenure committees are Bayesian, we would expect the slope of the relationship between
tenure committees are Bayesian, we would expect the slope of the relationship between
papers and tenure to be steeper for women. Put differently, if men and women received
papers and tenure to be steeper for women. Put differently, if men and women received
equal credit for papers, the coefficient onTotPapers
equal credit for papers, the coefficient onTotPapers
i
i
should be significantly larger for
should be significantly larger for
women than for men.
women than for men.
I provide a formal test for the difference in slopes for men and women in Column 1 of
We provide a formal test for the difference in slopes for men and women in Column 1
Table 2, where I present the estimates from
of Table 2, where we present the estimates from
T
T
if st
if st
1
1
TotPapers
TotPapers
i
i
2
2
fem
fem
i
i
3
3
(TotPapers
(TotPapers
i
i
×fem
×fem
i
i
) +β
) +β
4
4
TotPapers
TotPapers
2
2
i
Z
Z
i
i
f
f
s
s
t
t
+
+
if st
if st
(2)
(2)
This is similar to estimating equation 1 except that I interact total papers with a female
This is similar to estimating equation 1 except that we interact total papers with a female
dummy,fem
dummy,fem
i
i
rather than splitting the sample. There is no significant difference in the
rather than splitting the sample. There is no significant difference in the
marginal benefit of an additional paper to men and women.
marginal benefit of an additional paper to men and women.
3.1.2 The Tenure Gap and Paper Composition
3.1.2 The Tenure Gap and Paper Composition
To test whether coauthored papers matter differently for men and women, I separate pa-
To test whether coauthored papers matter differently for men and women, we separate
pers into those that are solo-authored and those that are coauthored and estimate
papers into those that are solo-authored and those that are coauthored and estimate
T
T
ifst
ifst
1
1
S
S
i
i
2
2
(fem
(fem
i
i
×S
×S
i
i
) +β
) +β
3
3
CA
CA
i
i
4
4
(fem
(fem
i
i
×CA
×CA
i
i
) +δ
) +δ
1
1
fem
fem
i
i
Z
Z
i
i
f
f
s
s
t
t
+
+
ifst
ifst
(3)
(3)
using OLS. Here,S
using OLS. Here,S
i
i
andCA
andCA
i
i
are the number of solo-authored and coauthored papers an
are the number of solo-authored and coauthored papers an
individual has at the time of tenure.
individual has at the time of tenure.
The results are presented in Table 2. An additional solo-authored paper is associated
The results are presented in Table 2. An additional solo-authored paper is associated
with a 9.7 percentage point increase in men’s tenure rates and a 15.4 percentage point
with a 9.7 percentage point increase in men’s tenure rates and a 15.4 percentage point
increase in women’s tenure rates (who start from a lower base tenure rate). If the lower
increase in women’s tenure rates (who start from a lower base tenure rate). If the lower
initial tenure rate for women is due to employers holding the belief that women are lower
initial tenure rate for women is due to employers holding the belief that women are lower
ability, it seems that the signals from solo papers begin to outweigh the employer’s prior.
This is consistent with a model in which employers start with a lower prior about women
9
9


ability, it seems that the signals from solo papers begin to outweigh the employer’s prior.
This is consistent with a model in which employers start with a lower prior about women
and update as they receive clear signals about a woman’s ability, giving women full credit
and update as they receive clear signals about a woman’s ability, giving women full credit
for this solo work. This is further discussed in the next section.
for this solo work. This is further discussed in the next section.
If coauthored papers are an unclear signal of ability, an employer must make a judg-
If coauthored papers are an
ment call as to how much each coauthor contributed to the paper which could lead to
differential attribution of credit. Indeed, we see that while an additional coauthored pa-
per helps both men and women, men benefit much more than women. Men’s tenure
rates increase by 8.2 percentage points when they produce a coauthored paper whereas
women’s increase by 5.6 percentage points.
However, the fact